ST 715 KN 0274
ST 715 KN 0274
2o
C. WEST CHURCHMAN
University of Berkeley
I Reprinted
Vol.
Management Technology
No. 1962
Printed in
Reprinted Management Technology
Vol. No. 1962
Printed in
University of Berkeley
Then came comfortable survival, so that it was irrational to getwet or cold when
one didn't have to. Then came intellectual survival, so that it was irrational not
to understand when one could understand.
This approach is very appealing on a number of grounds. It is more modest
than the moral precept. It doesn't say, "We have the final answer to rationality,"
but rather "This is rational as we see it today." It allows for a constant re-exami-
nation of the goals of man. Furthermore, in principle it permits objectivity, for
it allows us to ask an empirical question : how is man evolving? If we can under-
stand his evolution, we can understand what his rational goals really are. For
example, if democracy is at a more advanced evolutionary stage of man's social ..
development than totalitarianism, then we can say that the advocates of totali-
tarianism are irrational in today's world.
This theory of rationality made a lot of sense to the biologists of the nineteenth
and even the twentieth century. It also makes sense to today's evolutionary
industrial theorists. Modern industry began with very crude machinery, crudely
operated. After awhile men learned how to build better machines, but they
neglected the living standards of the worker. After awhile they were forced to
recognize a worker'sclaims, but theycouldn't figure out how to use him efficiently.
Along came industrial engineering, and efficiency went up. Along came automa-
tion, and it went up even more. Along came operations research, and even greater
refinements were introduced. At each stage we redeveloped our notion of rational
industrialization. Today we don't hesitate to say that a management that ignores
worker rights or uses old methods of manufacturing is "backward." We think
it is backward because it comes earlier in the evolutionary phases ofindustrializa-
tion. Those of us that are honest about it expect that we will look backward to
the industrial theorist of two decades from now. God knows how irrational our
methods may appear to be to the inhabitants of the twenty-third century.
It's all very happy thinking, this evolutionary concept of rationality. But it
also has much of the feeling of naivete about it. At times it seems to be saying
that any change is a good change, even if automation leads many citizens into
economic disaster, even if technology destroys individual creativeness, even if
science blows us all to our doom. The next stage of industrial evolution may be
1984, and therefore 1984 is rational! Get on with it at all costs; if change is pos-
sible, do it !
If we want to be honest, we have to admit that people are mean, arrogant, and
downright evil. Worst of all, they are stupid. They don't listen to good advice.
They don't want the other fellow to put anything over on them. They all want
to be politicians; big, important politicians who make the important decisions.
Some of the more shrewd want to be big scientists who will really make the im-
portant decisions. It can't be my decision if it's made in accordance with a strict
plan of development. It can't be very much at all if everyoneaccepts it as rational.
There is some comfort, it is true, in placing the responsibility for rationality
squarely in the hands of collective mankind, rather than in the individual con-
science. In a large world view, I can forget the crudities of my behavior and that
of my neighbor, because in the long sweep of things these crudities mean nothing.
ON RATIONAL 75
possible. But our concept of management science is that man can work on his
own evolution. He can work very hard on it, if he chooses to do so. One part of
this work consists of the use of research to develop better systems. But the sys-
tems are only better if managers are also involved.
The hint is this: the rational goals of man are those states that would evolve if
manager and scientist were to work together in bringing about change. "Work-
ing together" is an overworked phrase these days. But we have begun to evolve a
very special meaning of cooperation in the management sciences. This can be
expressed most succinctly as follows: management "works with" science when it
discovers how science can become a way of managing. When I say that science
can become a way of managing, I don't imply automation or any other form of
mechanical decision making, because none of these is science. Science is the
creative and systematic discovery of knowledge. In operations research we are
learning how science can be integrated into an organization in such a manner that
it acts as a management function. Operations research is the process of looking
at science as a management function.
The theme being developed here is this: a science that can only be conceived
as a discoverer of knowledge or a satisfier of intellectual curiosity is less rational
than a science that can be conceived as managing as well.
By the same token, we should be able to look at management as a scientific
function. This, indeed, is the manner in which research and development is
evolving in our times. We can no longer think of science as individual behavior;
it has clearly become a managed enterprise. As principles of the management of
science evolve, we can expect that what we have hitherto called "scientific
method" will become the management of science.
This is the hint as to the meaning of rationality: a social institution becomes
rational to the extent that it can be considered to function like some other in-
stitution. The evolution of the rationality of law will include the development of
law as a social science. The evolution of the rationality of politics will include
the development of politics as an educational system.
In other words, it is impossible to determine the rationality of conduct in
terms of one framework alone, as the "fixed principle" theory demands. Nor is
rational conduct simply a development along certain lines, as the evolutionary
theory suggests. The test of the rationality of an institution, or a company, or a
person, is the determination of the manner in which X functions as V, whatever
V may be.
In sum, I'm trying to say that a scientific study of behavior without sound
management can never determine the rationality of the behavior, just as a man-
agement activity without science can never become rational management.
f