314
314
INTRODUCTION
Introduction
Technological innovation has become an important part of the process by which companies
in many industries generate competitive advantage, making it a crucial part of firm strategy.
In recent years, many companies have increased their level of technological innovation to
produce a greater variety of new products, and to introduce those new products to market
faster. In many industries, the share of sales and profits accounted for by products introduced
in the past five years has been growing rapidly. In fact, some companies, like 3M, now
generate 40 per- cent of their sales from products that did not exist five years ago.
Companies have also increased their level of technological innovation in response to
competition. The reduction of costs and the improvement in quality of products made in
lower wage countries, like China and India, have posed a major challenge for firms in
developed countries, like the United States and Germany. Many firms from developed
countries have responded to this challenge by introducing new products at a faster pace to
stay ahead of imitators, and by using technological innovation to reduce their own production
costs.6
Technological innovation has also increased as more companies that once pro- duced
commodity products now seek to differentiate their offerings from those of competitors. The
desire of more companies to offer differentiated products has short- ened the product life
cycle and has increased the importance of investments in new product and process
development.7
Furthermore, technological innovation has increased as companies have turned intellectual
property into a marketable asset. In recent years, the licensing of tech- nology to other
companies has become an important revenue stream for many com- panies, with some, like
IBM, adopting the approach that all of its intellectual property is potentially for sale. This
marks a major change from only a couple of decades ago when intellectual property was used
only as an input into a company’s product or service.
In addition, there has been significant growth recently in the formation of high- technology
start-ups that use funding by venture capitalists and business angels (individuals who invest
their own money in start-up companies, usually by taking an equity stake in them) to
introduce high-technology products and compete with established firms. As a result,
technological innovation has also been increasing because of entrepreneurs, including those
who create spin-off companies, using tech- nology developed at major corporations and
universities.
This emphasis on technological innovation as a way to generate or preserve competitive
advantage has led to an increased need for managers and entrepre- neurs who can develop
strategies to successfully manage this activity. While com- panies can, and do, introduce new
products, improve production processes, and target new markets without strategies or plans,
companies are better at these activities if they develop, and execute, an effective strategy to
undertake them.8 By combining an understanding of markets and technological evolution
with an understanding of firm organization and capabilities in a deliberate and organized
manner, managers and entrepreneurs can generate value by developing technol- ogy products
and services that better meet customer needs, and can become better at capturing that value.
The increased need for managers and entrepreneurs to develop strategies for technological
innovation, in turn, has led to an increased demand for business school courses in the
management of technological innovation, and for strategic
Earning a return on investment: mechanisms for ensuring that value is captured from
innovation
INTRODUCTION
Capturing Value from Innovation
Companies often use technological innovation to enhance their competitive position relative
to their rivals.4 Doing this successfully requires capturing the returns to their investment in
innovation because innovating cannot provide a competitive advan- tage if other companies
derive the benefits from it. Take, for example, the case of Palm Computing. Although the
company developed an innovative personal digital assistant that customers valued a lot, the
company created no barriers to imitation. As a result, competitors copied many of Palm’s
valuable innovations and stole many of its customers.5
So how can you deter imitation of your innovative new products and services? While you can
sometimes use the legal mechanisms, often these mechanisms are not available or not very
effective, and you need to take other approaches, such as exploiting the lead time advantages
discussed in the opening vignette.
This chapter focuses on the nonlegal ways that companies appropriate the returns to
investment in innovation. The first section identifies several key mecha- nisms that you can
use to capture the profits from innovation, including controlling resources, obtaining
architectural control, developing a brand name reputation, moving up the learning curve,
being a first mover, and taking advantage of economies of scale. The second section brings
together the intellectual property issues with the issues discussed earlier in this chapter to
present a model of when to be an imitator, and focus on the control of complementary assets,
and when to be an innovator, and focus on the introduction of new products.
APPROPRIABILITY MECHANISMS
Developing an innovative new product or service often requires you to invest in R&D, which
is costly. This investment makes sense if you can appropriate, or cap- ture, the financial
returns from it.6 However, if you cannot capture those returns, then the investment in
innovation makes little sense at all.
While you can block imitation and thus appropriate the returns to innovation by using the
legal mechanisms, you will often need to use nonlegal barriers to imi- tation. First, legal
barriers to imitation cannot be obtained for many products and services. Take for example,
the case of a superior snowboard binding design. You will be unable to patent that design
unless you can prove that it is novel and nonob- vious, and even then, the patent office might
deny your patent application or refuse to give you broad and enforceable claims. You also
will be unable to protect the design as a trade secret because it could be easily identified
through reverse engi- neering. Therefore, to capture the returns to your investment in
developing this new design, you would need some type of nonlegal barrier to imitation.
Second, most nonlegal barriers to imitation are more effective at deterring inno- vation than
legal barriers.7 As Table 1 shows, managers in high-technology indus- tries believe that
patents deter imitation a little more than a third of the time; whereas complementary assets in
manufacturing and marketing block imitation over 43 percent of the time, and lead time does
so approximately half of the time
Third, legal and nonlegal barriers are not mutually exclusive. You can combine the two
simultaneously, as would occur if you developed a trade secret and moved up the learning
curve, or sequentially, as would occur if you used a patent to protect your new product until
you had established a brand name.
Fourth, the degree of protection provided by legal mechanisms in certain techni- cal areas,
such as genetics and Internet business methods, are uncertain. Changing legislation and
unresolved legal issues can make relying on legal mechanisms to deter imitation in these
areas risky. You might invest heavily in obtaining patent pro- tection only to find that it
doesn’t have the effect that you thought that it would have because legislation or court
decisions subsequently limited the strength of that protection.
Fifth, technological change itself has weakened the value of the legal barriers to imitation in
many high-technology industries. For instance, the creation of technol- ogy to facilitate the
exchange of video and audio content on the Internet, such as that used by video-sharing Web
sites or peer-to-peer music networks, makes the enforce- ment of copyrights on video and
audio content much more difficult. By dramatically increasing the number of people who
violate copyrights, and dramatically reducing the average size of each violation, these
technological changes have essentially reduced the value of lawsuits as a deterrent to
imitation. Violators know that the odds they will get caught and sued is very small.
Because you cannot rely only on legal barriers to imitation, you need to learn how to employ
nonlegal mechanisms to protect your innovations, including controlling key resources,
creating a brand name reputation, establishing architectural control, exploiting of economies
of scale, moving up the learning curve, and exploiting first mover advantages.
Controlling Key Resources
One way to deter imitation and appropriate the returns to your investment in inno- vation is
by obtaining control over the key resources needed to create and sell your product or service.
These key resources will vary across industries and can include such things as manufacturing
facilities (e.g., a billion-dollar semiconduc- tor fab), distribution channels (e.g., shelf space in
a supermarket),9 key inputs (e.g., part of the communication spectrum),10 and the patents,
copyrights, trademarks, and trade secrets. For example, if you run an oil company, you might
want to purchase, or sign long-term contracts with, all of the low-cost sources of oil. This
would create a barrier to imitation by insuring that you had a lower cost of oil than your
competi- tors.11 Similarly, if you run a biotechnology company, you might want to buy the
patents necessary to produce the drug that you are developing from the university where it
was invented to make sure that your competitors cannot get access to this resource.
The use of resource control as a barrier to imitation does not require the key resources to be
natural resources, or even physical resources.12 They could easily be human resources. While
you can’t buy up all of the key human resources needed to create and distribute your product,
you can still obtain control over those resources through contracting. For example, if you run
a biotechnology company, you could sign long-term employment contracts with all of the top
genetic engineers in the world so that you had control over their talent, which is a rare
resource in drug development.13
Controlling resources is most effective at deterring imitation when the key resource is rare
and also a rival good, which keeps it from being used by two com- panies simultaneously.14
If the resource meets these two conditions, you can deter imitation by gaining control over
just a few sources of supply. For example, you can deter imitation in cellular communications
by licensing part of the radio. Establishing a Reputation
A second way that you can appropriate the returns to your investment in innovation is by
developing a reputation for satisfying customers.16 When value of a new prod- uct’s
attributes is unknown, customers often look to the reputation of the seller as an indication of
that value.17 As a result, companies with stronger brand names can attract customers to their
new products more easily than companies with weaker reputations. For example, when IBM
developed its first personal computer, it was able to attract business customers much more
easily than its competitors because of its reputation as a leading computer manufacturer.18
In addition, by creating a strong brand name, you can generate the perception in the minds of
customers that your product or service is better than those offered by your competitors. This
mitigates the tendency for your customers to shift to competi- tors’ products or services, even
if they can obtain those products or services at a lower price. For instance, Apple Computer
has sought to convince customers that its products are better than those of its competitors by
stressing its brand and its reputa- tion for design excellence.
Furthermore, you can use a brand name to cross-sell products into new mar- kets. If your
brand becomes known for something in one area, such as value or excellent engineering, you
can leverage that customer perception in other markets. For example, Microsoft has used its
brand name to sell video games.19 Even though Microsoft had no proven ability in making
video games when it first introduced those games, its brand name led consumers to believe
that its video games would be very good.
Of course, the effectiveness of using reputation to capture the returns to invest- ment in
innovation varies greatly across industries. Reputation matters more in industries that serve
consumers than industries that serve businesses because busi- nesses are less likely to be
swayed by perceptions than by the economics of a transac- tion. Moreover, among industries
that serve consumers, brand names are most effective in industries, such as fashion, in which
customer behavior is more heavily influenced by perceptions, and in industries in which
advertising is more important in affecting buying decisions.
Developing a brand name is expensive. To build one, you have to invest in advertising, which
provides information to customers about the qualities of your new product or service and
persuades them that these qualities make the product or service better than those offered by
competitors. Because the price of develop- ing and running a radio, television, or print
advertisement tends to be fixed, regardless of how many units you produce, advertising is
subject to considerable economies of scale. Therefore, advertising is very expensive on a per
unit basis if you produce and sell very few units of a product, but falls as your volume
increases.
Moreover, it takes a long time to build a reputation though advertising. The nature of the
human mind is such that it can only process a certain amount of infor- mation at a time,
whether that information comes from advertising or some other source. As a result, people do
not absorb much from an ad each time they see it. For advertising to be truly effective,
repeated messages need to be sent over a long period of time. This means that you have to
invest in advertising for a while before you can see any benefits from it.
Obtaining Architectural Control
A third way that you can deter imitation and appropriate the returns to your investment in
innovation is by developing architectural control, or control over the operation and
compatibility of a product or service. Architectural control allows you to determine what
products and services work with your own, making it possible to bias compatibility toward
your own products. Moreover, it allows you to manage the type and pace of improvements to
your technology to ensure that improvements benefit you and not your competitors. For
example, Microsoft has been able to influence the development of computer software to favor
its prod- ucts at the expense of its competitors’ products because it has architectural control
over the dominant interface between computer hardware and software, the Windows
operating system.22
Architectural control also permits you to maximize your profits from the sale of older
versions of products before the introduction of newer ones. Microsoft’s archi- tectural control
in personal computer operating systems allows it to time the intro- duction of new
generations of operating system software to maximize customer upgrades and minimize the
cannibalization of its sales.
When companies have architectural control, they are generally very successful at bundling.
Bundling allows companies to combine old products of known value to customers with new
products of unknown value to increase the odds that customers will adopt the new products.
When a company has architectural control, the effectiveness of a bundling strategy is
enhanced because the old product that is part of the bundle is not only known, it is also
critical to customers. For example, Microsoft used its architec- tural control over the
Windows operating system to push its Web browser for- ward at the expense of Netscape’s
Navigator. By bundling its Web browser with its operating system, Microsoft essentially
forced computer manufacturers to adopt its Web browser as the one that they would offer on
the computers that they sold.23
Exploiting Economies of Scale
Another way to deter imitation and appropriate the returns to your investment in innovation is
by exploiting economies of scale, the reduction in unit costs that occurs as production volume
increases. When economies of scale exist, larger firms have a lower cost of production than
smaller firms, which allows them to deter imitation by keeping their prices low. For example,
the capital intensity of the semiconductor business means that Intel, which is larger than other
firms in the industry, can produce new generations of semiconductors at much lower unit
costs than its competitors.
Larger firms can also deter imitation by investing in so much capacity that entry into the
industry by other firms would be unprofitable. Because volume pro- duction reduces costs
dramatically, new entrants have to enter on a large scale to match the cost structure of
existing competitors. This means that their entry will create a large amount of excess
capacity, dragging down prices, and reducing prof- its.24 Faced with the prospect that entry
will be unprofitable, imitators often choose not to enter.
For example, Monsanto is the world’s largest producer of glycophosate, the active ingredient
in herbicides, like Roundup. Because the production of glycophos- phate requires high levels
of capital investment, production is subject to scale economies. By operating at a very large
scale, Monsanto has driven production costs so low that it is cheaper for companies to source
glycophosate from Monsanto than to produce it on their own, which keeps other companies
from entering the gly- cophosphate business.25
In general, economies of scale provide more of a barrier to imitation for large, established
firms than for small, new ones. The advantages of scale economies go to those companies
that have more scale, which tend not to be the new ones. While new companies can
sometimes be created at a larger size than established competitors, most of the time, the cost,
risk, and difficulty of creating a new company on a large scale means that new companies
usually are smaller than established companies in the businesses that they enter.
Moving Up the Learning Curve
You can deter imitation and appropriate the returns to your investment in innovation by
moving up the learning curve. (A learning curve is a graphical depiction of how well
someone does at something as a function of the number of times that they have done it.26)
Moving up the learning curve helps you to deter imitation for two reasons. First, as Figure 3
indicates, by doing more of something than your competi- tors, you become better at it than
them. (You produce more output at a lower input cost.27) As a result, your competitors
cannot produce a new product with the same efficiency as you, and so choose not to copy
what you are doing.
For example, as semiconductor firms produce more semiconductors, they learn how to solve
problems that lead to poor yields. As a result, their production yields— the proportion of
products that meet performance standards—improve with the vol- ume produced. Because of
the capital intensity and complexity of the process of making semiconductors, the advantage
that innovators have in increasing produc- tion yields makes copying their efforts
uneconomical, making the learning curve an important barrier to imitation in this industry.
Second, as you gain experience making and selling a product, you learn how to create
features that your competitors cannot match. The inability of your competitors to match your
product deters imitation because customers do not find their alterna- tives as appealing as
yours. For example, many consumer electronics firms have learned how to make their
products smaller and more robust to wear-and-tear through the process of producing and
selling the devices. Other companies have been unsuccessful at copying these products
because their lack of experience keeps them from providing similar features. Your ability to
use the learning curve to deter imitation depends on your ability to learn from experience. If
your organization has a lot of employee turnover; poor mechanisms for capturing learning; an
inability to access information that already has been learned; or has poor mechanisms for
transferring knowledge internally, then it will be poor at learning from experience. As a
result, your organization will be unable to use the learning curve to appropriate the returns to
innovation.29
In addition, you can only use the learning curve to appropriate the returns to innovation if
learning is proprietary. If what you have learned seeps out to other companies in your
industry, then your competitors will know whatever you know, equalizing their performance
with yours, even if they have less experience. For instance, many early Internet clothing start-
ups were unable to generate learning curve advantages because later start-ups learned what
those entrants had figured out about how to get people to buy clothing online simply by
observing the efforts of the early entrants. The learning curve is more effective at deterring
imitation in some industries than in others because more of the knowledge that provides value
in those industries is tacit. For example, much of the knowledge about how to make aircraft is
tacit, and held in the brains of aerospace engineers, while most of the knowledge about com-
puter networking is codified in books, articles, and patents.31 As a result, the learning curve
is a stronger deterrent to imitation in aerospace than in computer networking.
As you have probably already figured out, the learning curve is a much better mechanism to
appropriate the returns to investment in innovation for established companies than for new
ones. By definition, any learning curve advantages that exist go to the companies that have
produced more of a product. Therefore, estab- lished companies, which have been operating
in an industry longer than new com- panies, tend to have the learning curve advantages. The
only exception to this occurs when all of the learning resides in the head of individuals, as
might be the case in, say, IT consulting. In that industry, if all of the experienced employees
quit an established consulting company to start their own, the new company might end up
higher on the learning curve than the old one because it would have the more experienced
consultants.
Exploiting a First Mover Advantage (Lead Time)
A sixth way that you can deter imitation and appropriate the returns to your invest- ment in
innovation is by exploiting a first mover advantage, or the advantage that accrues to a
company from being the first to enter a market. Several studies have shown that first movers
often are able to obtain a higher market share32 and earn higher profits than later entrants.33
First Mover Advantages
Being a first mover can help you to appropriate the returns to investment in innova- tion in
several ways. First, by moving early, you are more likely to obtain control over key
resources. For instance, you can acquire assets that are in limited supply,34 such as the most
attractive physical locations, the best distribution channels, or the least expensive sources of
raw materials and other inputs.35 In addition, you can work to reduce your costs of
production by moving up the learning curve unfettered by competition before other firms can
reap the benefits of learning.36 Furthermore, you can tip the industry toward your product
before competitors can catch up, as Apple appears to have done in the music download
business with its early introduc- tion of the iPod.37
Second, by moving first, you can target the best customers in a market. By selling your
products to the innovators and early adopters, you will leave only potential customers who
are negatively disposed to adopting new products, making it hard for imitators to sell their
products successfully.38 Moreover, as a first mover, when you first enter a market, you will
have a monopoly on promoting your products. Therefore, you can advertise without
customers hearing competing messages,39 making your advertising more effective.
Third, as a first mover, you can exploit switching costs, or the cost to customers of changing
suppliers. While moving first doesn’t guarantee that you can create switching costs, it is a
necessary condition. If you are a late mover, then someone else will have the opportunity to
create switching costs that create obstacles for cus- tomers to change from its products to
yours.
Switching costs can take a variety of different forms. Sometimes, they take the form of the
additional expense necessary to purchase a replacement product. These costs can be
particularly high when products are bundled and other products must also be changed if
suppliers are replaced. For example, for a long time, customers were deterred from switching
from Apple to Microsoft as a supplier of graphics soft- ware because changing to Windows-
based software also required changing com- puter hardware.
Other times, switching costs exist because it is costly for customers to learn a new system.
For example, many hospitals use particular intravenous solution deliv- ery systems because
nurses have learned to use those systems, and it is too costly for the hospitals to retrain them
to use different systems. For instance, Amazon.com is the default choice for most customers
who buy books online. Customers switch suppliers only when Amazon.com fails to satisfy
their needs.48 As a result, Amazon.com has to spend less money to keep its customers than
its competitors have to spend to woo them away.
Late Mover Advantages
Despite the advantages listed previously, moving first is not always a good strategy. As Table
2 shows, many late movers have been more successful than early movers. For instance,
Google was a late entrant in Internet search but has done better than Lycos, the first mover.
Similarly, many other first movers have been less successful than their late moving
competitors, including Netscape in the Web browser busi- ness,49 VisiCalc in the spreadsheet
business,50 and Apple in the PDA market.51 In fact, one study showed that first movers have
a high—47 percent—failure rate and achieve only about 10 percent market share.52
Why are late movers sometimes more successful than first movers? The answer is that being
a late mover provides several advantages to companies. First, as a late mover, you benefit
from the ability to free ride on the investments that the first mover makes in creating supply
infrastructure and distribution channels.53 For instance, when DEKA Research developed its
IBOT wheelchair, it had to create its own ball bearings because no company could supply it
with the ones it needed.54 By the time later movers had entered the industry, however, other
com- panies had figured out how to provide these ball bearings, reducing the cost of sourcing
supply.
Second, as a late mover, you can design products that correct the mistakes that the first mover
has made in meeting customer needs.55 First movers often face cus- tomers who do not know
what features they want in new products or services, or what they will pay for them, while
later movers face customers that are better edu- cated about the product category.56 The
lower uncertainty about customer prefer- ences faced by later movers allows them to design
products that better fit customer needs.57
Third, as a late mover, you can leapfrog ahead of the first mover’s technology.58 Often, first
movers cannot adapt to changing supply or demand conditions, and are unable to develop
products based on a new generation of technology because they are locked into earlier
product designs or process technologies.59 As a result, later movers can often develop better
products and production processes than first movers. For example, later movers in personal
computers benefited from the changes in customer preferences to which Osborne Computer,
the industry pio- neer, could not respond because it had already committed to a particular
techno- logical approach that was incompatible with these changes.
Fourth, as a late mover, you can benefit from the investments in R&D that the first mover has
made. Because knowledge spills over from the first mover to later movers, the cost of
innovation is higher than the cost of imitation. As a result, first movers spend more money
than later movers to develop comparable new prod- ucts.61 Therefore, you may be better off
entering a market late, particularly if the technology underlying a new product is costly to
develop and inexpensive to imitate.
Fifth, as a later mover, your entry into the market is often better timed to take advantage of
the development of complementary technology than the first mover’s entry, which sometimes
occurs before the complementary technology has had a chance to develop. For example, to
have hydrogen fuel cell vehicles, someone first needs to figure out how to store compressed
hydrogen in pressurized tanks at fueling stations. A first mover that enters the market before
this refueling problem is resolved would face very slow adoption of its vehicles, and might be
worse off than a later mover that enters after the problem had been solved.
First Mover or Late Mover?
So how do you know if you should be a first mover or a late mover? The answer depends on
your industry. The following dimensions of industry affect this choice:
• First,youarebetteroffbeingafirstmoverinindustriesinwhichproductsand services are
expensive, cannot be valued easily prior to purchase, are durable, and are infrequently
purchased.63 In these industries, once customers have adopted a product, they are not likely
to repurchase it very soon. As a result, first movers are likely to remove the best customers
from the market before later movers have a chance to sell to them.
• Second,youarebetteroffbeingafirstmoverinadvertising-intensiveindus- tries, and industries in
which customers learn very little or very slowly about new products.64 In these industries, it
is very difficult to persuade customers to switch from the first mover’s product to the later
mover’s version. As a result, first movers face a much lower cost to attract customers than
later movers.
• Third,youarebetteroffbeingafirstmoverinindustriesinwhichproducts require distributors to
hold large stocks, additional parts, or complementary products to satisfy the needs of end
users.65 In these industries, later movers often find it difficult to obtain access to distribution
channels because the dis- tributors lack the space to handle the later mover’s product in
addition to the first mover’s.
• Fourth, you are better off being a first mover in industries where network externalities exist.
In these industries, the first mover has the opportunity to build an installed base and tip the
market to its product before later movers have a chance to compete.
Fifth, in industries in which patents are more effective.67 In these industries, first movers
have the chance to develop pioneering patents that later movers cannot get around.
• Sixth, in industries in which scale economies are very large.68 In these industries, moving
first will allow you to grow large and drive your costs down before your competitors can
introduce an alternative product.
Key Points
• Companies need to determination to appropriate the returns to investment-in innovation.
• Non legal mechanisms—controlling key resources, exploiting economies-of scale, moving
up the learning curve, being a first mover, building a brand name reputation, and establishing
architectural control—help companies to do this.
• Non legal barriers to imitation are valuable because legal and non legal barriers are not
mutually exclusive, and legal barriers cannot always be obtained, are of uncertain value in
some fields, are less effective than nonlegal barriers in most industries, and because
technological change has weakened their value in some industries.
• Controlling key resources is most effective when resources are revival goods.
• By exploiting economies of scale, companies can reduce their costs below their
competitors’, and make entry by other firms unprofitable.
• By moving up the learning curve, companies become more efficient at-making products and
develop product features that competitors cannot match.
• Learningcurveadvantagesexistonlyiflearningisproprietaryandfirmsare good at learning.
• By building a reputation, companies can attract customers more easily and keep them from
shifting suppliers; however, brand names are more effective at appropriating the returns to
investment in innovation in industries that serve consumers, particularly those that are
strongly affected by perception.
• Architecturalcontrolallowsfirmstolimitcompatibilityoftheirproductsto companies that are not
a competitive threat, to bias compatibility to their own products, and to control the type and
pace of product improvement.
• Beingafirstmoveroffersavarietyofadvantagesanddisadvantagestofirms; whether it is better to
be a first mover or a later mover depends on which indus- try you are in.
TEECE’S MODEL
Many companies do not succeed with efforts to introduce innovative products because their
competitors imitate those products and offer their versions at a lower cost, taking customers
(and profits) away from the innovators.69 This means that you need to figure out when you
are better off being an innovator and developing new products, and when you are better off
being an imitator and letting your competitors develop them. David Teece, a professor at the
Haas School of Business at the University of California at Berkeley, has developed a model
that you can use to make this decision. The model is based on the idea that imitators are more
successful than innovators when innovations are easy to imitate, a dominant design has
Teece’s Model
Capturing Value from Innovation
When using Teece’s model, decision makers first need to determine if the industry is one in
which patents or trade secrets are effective, then determine if convergence on a dominant
design has occurred, and then if the value chain assets are specialized or generic.
emerged in an industry, and imitators control the key complementary assets in the industry.
We need to define complementary assets to explain Teece’s model. Complementary assets are
upstream or downstream assets that are used to develop, produce, or distribute an innovative
new product or service.70 For example, Merck’s pharmaceutical sales force, which numbers
in the thousands and can reach most doc- tors in the world; Sony’s specialized facilities for
producing high-definition televi- sions; and Bristol Myers Squibb’s process of conducting
drug clinical trials and obtaining FDA approval are all complementary assets because they are
all used along with the innovations themselves to generate and capture value from innovating.
Difficult to Imitate
Innovators usually do not lose out to imitators in industries in which imitation of new
products and services is difficult. Therefore, the first step in applying Teece’s model is to
determine how difficult it is to imitate new products and services in your industry. To do this,
you want to look at the effectiveness of patents and trade secrets in your industry (perhaps by
examining data which shows patent effectiveness in different industries). In industries in
which patents or trade secrets are very effective at deter- ring imitation, being an innovator is
a good idea. The barriers to imitation afforded by patents or trade secrets will allow you to
keep your competitors from copying your new products, adjust the design of your new
products if market feedback suggests that such changes are necessary,71 and build or contract
for the complementary assets needed to exploit the innovations.72 For example, being an
innovator is a good idea in biotechnology because companies can exploit the effectiveness of
drug patents to compete successfully with imitators.
INTRODUCTION
Because many industries converge on technical standards, understanding their role in
business is important to the accurate formulation of technology strategy. For instance, you
need to understand how technical standards affect customer adoption of new products. You
may need to fight a standard-setting battle. And you certainly will need to adopt strategies
that are appropriate to the outcome of the standard-setting process to make your business
successful.
This chapter discusses the creation and exploitation of technical standards. The first section
defines a technical standard, and explains how standards develop, why they aren’t always the
best technology, and how their formation relates to customer adoption. The second section
examines standard-setting battles. It explains how to win a standards battle, and what to do if
you lose one. It also explains why technical
Technical Standards
standards shift the locus of competition from firms to systems of firms and identifies the way
that the shift affects strategy. The final section compares open and closed technical standards
and explains how technology strategy differs depending on the openness of the industry
standard.
TECHNICAL STANDARD
There is the concept of a dominant design, or form of a product on which all producers
converge. A related, but broader, concept is that of technical standards, which are
specifications to ensure that different components of the same system are compatible For
example, the electrical plug is designed to specifications that ensure that it will work in all
electrical outlets.
Technical standards are important in a wide variety of industries, from comput- ers to
transportation to telecommunications, because they permit independent com- panies to
produce different components for the same product. They exist when components made by
one company need to be used with components made by another because companies cannot
ensure that components made by others will be compatible, unless they are made to conform
to a standard. For instance, in comput- ers, technical standards permit hardware, printers,
software, memory chips, and peripheral devices that are produced by different companies to
all work together.3 As Figure 2 highlights, technical standards in measurement are
particularly important.
Technical standards are particularly important to start-up firms. While large, established
companies can make all of the components in a product and avoid prob- lems with the lack of
established technical standards, start-ups usually lack the capi- tal to do this. Because start-
ups usually cannot produce all of the components in a product, they need technical standards
to ensure that their products are compatible with complementary products.
The Development of Technical Standards and Dominant Designs
Research has shown that technical standards and dominant designs develop in a variety of
ways. Sometimes, chance occurrence leads them to emerge. For example, some researchers
argue that the all-steel body in automobiles emerged as a domi- nant design just because
aluminum was relatively costly in comparison to steel in the 1920s.4
The emergence of a technical standard or dominant design also depends, at least in part, on
the nature of technology. Some technical solutions are better than others, and the best
technical solution sometimes emerges.5 For example, nylon and poly- ester emerged as the
dominant designs in synthetic fiber because they have the chemical composition to produce
long fibers, which is useful in making fabric.6 Similarly, suspension-preheating became the
dominant design in cement manufac- ture because it was the most fuel-efficient alternative.7
Sometimes governments impose technical standards and dominant designs.8 For example, the
European Union adopted the GSM wireless telephony standard to ensure that people in all the
countries of the Union had compatible mobile phones.
Other times, the government does not impose a technical standard or a domi- nant design, but
influences its adoption nonetheless. Typically, this happens when the government serves as an
early adopter of a product and creates a large installed base—the number of users of a
product at a point in time—for a particular variant.9 For example, the U.S. government could
make a particular type of fuel cell vehicle the technical standard by purchasing those vehicles
for the military, postal service, and other government agencies.
Governments often get involved in setting technical standards or dominant designs when
companies have little incentive to adopt a new technology. Take, for example, the case of
high-definition television. Broadcasters have little incentive to switch to the new technology
because it is unlikely that the audience for televi- sion, and hence advertising revenues, will
increase as a result.10 And television users do not want to adopt the new technology until the
price of high-definition televisions comes close to that of traditional televisions, and
programs are pro- duced in high definition. Because the market has no mechanism to spur a
shift to high-definition television, government mandate is the only way to put the new
technology in place.11
Industry trade associations or standard-setting organizations sometimes create technical
standards and dominant designs, usually through votes of committee mem- bers that are
selected by their employers to represent them on working groups. For example, an
international organization called the International Telecommunication Union.
Companies sometimes cooperate with other firms to create a technical stan- dard or dominant
design.14 The logic of this approach is that if companies cooper- ate with others to jointly
develop a common standard, they will attract customers more quickly. If the cooperating
companies are large enough, other companies will often go along with their approach, and the
common standard will be adopted. For instance, Philips and Sony worked together to develop
a standard for compact disk technology that was favorable to both of them; the size of the two
companies led other companies to go along, rather than pursue a rival standard, and
convinced the music labels to provide content that adhered to the Philips-Sony standard.
However, many firms, even large firms, fail at strategic efforts to make their tech- nology the
industry standard, as occurred when IBM backed a standard for local area networking, but
lost out to Ethernet. This raises the question: Is investing in efforts to establish and control a
technical standard worthwhile? Given the significant chance that you will fail at this effort,
investing a lot of money in trying to do so might not be a good strategy. You might be better
off simply accepting the evolution of a technical standard and adopting a strategy that best
fits it.
Not Always the Best Technology
As you can probably tell from the description of the different ways that technical standards
develop, the technology that becomes the industry standard is not always the “best”
technology from the perspective of functionality.17 Often, it is technically inferior to the
other alternatives available.
The “best” technology doesn’t always become the industry standard for many reasons,
including government mandate, the strategic actions of firms, agreement by standard-setting
bodies, or social support for a particular alternative.19 For example, in automobiles, the
internal combustion engine emerged as the dominant design, rather than the electric battery
engine, which many observers thought was techni- cally superior, in part because the electric
battery engine needed recharging, which made it less popular for touring, a major social use
of the automobile at the begin- ning of the twentieth century.20
Nevertheless, the most common way that industries converge on technically inferior
alternatives is through the natural workings of the market.21 If a technology achieves a large
installed base, later adopters will tend to choose this technology even if it is inferior to
alternatives that emerge later.
The QWERTY typewriter keyboard (named for the order of letters on the top line) is a good
example. The QWERTY keyboard was designed initially to slow typ- ing, which was
important with the jamming-prone typewriters of the 1880s. Once this technical problem was
resolved, however, typing performance could be enhanced by the adoption of different
keyboard designs. In fact, one of these key- boards, patented by Dvorak and Dealey in 1932,
was so good that the costs of retrain- ing typists to use it could be amortized in 10 days. Yet,
despite the performance advantages of the alternative keyboard designs, they have never been
adopted in large numbers because the installed base of QWERTY keyboards has always been
too large to make widespread switching possible.
Technical Standards and Customer Adoption
The emergence of a technical standard is important to attract customers in large vol- ume.
Customers are risk averse and do not want to adopt products that might be abandoned or
discontinued because the products are incompatible with a technology that becomes the
industry standard.23 As a result, customers are often slow to adopt new products until a
technical standard is in place.24 For instance, adoption of high- definition DVDs has been
slow because their producers have been unable to agree upon a common standard, with two
groups battling over competing Blu-ray and HD-DVD alternatives.
Technical standards are particularly important to the customer adoption deci- sion when
products are systemic. Because systemic products are composed of com- ponents that need to
be used with other components, having a common standard is important in ensuring that
components produced by different companies can be used together. For example, the
adoption of digital cameras did not take off until technical standards for the different camera
components had been established because these cameras are made up of an image gathering
device, a processing device, a storage device, and a reproduction device, all of which are
produced by dif- ferent companies.
Technical standards also enhance customer adoption by making many prod- ucts more
functional.25 For example, imagine how difficult it would be to use a telephone if the people
you wanted to call had a telephone that operated on a dif- ferent technical standard from
yours. You wouldn’t be able to speak to them. And if there were multiple telephone standards,
you would probably get pretty frustrated because ou would only be able to call a small
portion of the people that you wanted to reach.
Standardisation also enhances customer adoption because it facilitates the creation of
complementary products.26 The existence of a technical standard permits companies to make
products that work with those developed by other companies, increasing the number of
products available to customers. Take Web sites, for example. Because all Web sites are
created in accordance with a common technical standard, consumers have Web sites that are
produced by millions, if not billions, of entities when they browse on their computers. The
greater availability of Web sites makes Web surfing a more useful, and enjoyable, activity.
Key Points
• In some industries, products must conform-to technical standard-or specifications that
ensure that different components are compatible.
• Standards are of particular importance to start-up firms, which generally cannot produce all
of the components needed to make a product.
• Technical standards develop because of chance occurrence, because one tech- nology is
superior to others, because the installed base of one technology is far ahead of the installed
base of others, because companies take strategic action, because industry trade associations or
standard-setting bodies establish them, and because governments mandate them.
• Industriessometimesconvergeonstandardsthataretechnicallyinferiorto other alternatives.
• Technicalstandardsinfluencecustomeradoptionbecausecustomersdesire compatibility,
particularly for systemic products.
STANDARDS BATTLES
Where technical standards exist, your company will have a tremendous advantage and the
potential to earn high profits if your proprietary technology is the industry standard. There are
several reasons why. Products that conform to the technical stan- dard can be sold at a
premium given their greater value to customers. These higher prices create higher profit
margins and give you the opportunity to generate out- sized financial returns. Moreover, if
your technology becomes the industry standard, your suppliers will have to adhere to it,
giving you leverage over them, and allowing you to capture a large portion of industry
profits. Furthermore, your competitors will have to adopt your technology, which puts them
at a competitive disadvantage.
Because gaining control over a standard is valuable to companies, battles for technical
standards have long been a part of technology strategy. In the nineteenth century, for instance,
railroads fought over whether the technical standard for rail- way gauges should be 4 feet 8.5
inches wide or 5 feet wide; and in the 1940s, CBS and NBC fought over the technical
standard for color televisions
How to Win a Standards Battle
So what can you do to win a standards battle? First, you can gain the support of the producers
of complementary products. If all other things are equal, one technical standard will be
preferred to another if more complementary products are available for that standard. Why?
Because the availability of complementary products makes a given product more valuable to
customers.
In the high-definition DVD war, for example, the Blu-ray faction, led by Sony, and the HD-
DVD faction, led by Toshiba, are each working to gain the support of the movie studios,
which provide content for their version of the high definition DVD player (see Figure 3).
Each faction offers different advantages to those comple- mentors, which it stresses to
convince them to support its standard. Blu-ray offers greater recording capacity and
protection against illegal copying, while HD-DVD offers a manufacturing process that
requires few changes from conventional DVDs
Second, you can make your product backward compatible so that it works with a previous
generation of products. (If products are not backward compatible, they won’t work with
previous generations of technology, as is the case with MP3 players and CDs.) For example,
the backers of both competing standards for high- definition DVDs, Blu-ray, and HD-DVD,
have made their products compatible with standard DVD players.30 Backward compatibility
helps you win a standards battle by facilitating customer adoption of your new product. As
was mentioned earlier in the chapter, customers often do not adopt a new technology product
because they are afraid that the product will be useless if the new technology does not
become the industry standard. By making your product backward compatible, you reduce the
cost to customers of choosing the wrong technology—they can always use it with the
previous generation of technology—and enhance their will- ingness to buy your new product.
However, making a new product backward compatible is expensive, and there- fore, not
always worthwhile. It also reduces the incentive for the producers of com- plementary
products to make their products unique. If complementary products are not unique to your
product, then customers will derive less benefit from switching to your new product, and will
be less likely to do so.31
Furthermore, making your product backward compatible might undermine its unique
advantages over other products on the market. For instance, Intel made its 486 processor
using complex instruction set computer (CISC) architecture as opposed to reduced instruction
set computer (RISC) architecture so that it would be backward compatible with earlier
generations of personal computers. While this approach made its customers more comfortable
adopting the new processor, it also meant that Intel could not take advantage of the greater
scalability, faster product development time, and better performance of the RISC processor.32
As a result, the 486 processor offered less of an advantage over rival processors than it could
have.
Third, you can manage customer and competitor expectations.33 Customers are influenced
not just by reality but by their perceptions about products, their installed base, and the
availability of complementary products. Because a small advantage in the early life of a
market can lead customers to tip to a particular product, you can often win a standards battle
by changing customer perceptions through the manage- ment of information.
You can manage customer expectations by making pronouncements about the size of your
installed base. Because potential customers favor products with larger installed base,
companies frequently try to convince customers that they have a larger market share than
their competitors. For example, in the early 1990s, Sega and Nintendo each claimed they
controlled over 60 percent of the video game market, knowing that future customer adoptions
would go dispro- portionately to the product that customers perceived as dominant.
You can also manage customer and competitor expectations by making prod- uct
preannouncements, or announcements of product release dates before the actual release
occurs. Preannouncements help to manage expectations in several ways:
• First,theyhelpconvincecompetitorsthattheyaresofarbehindtheannouncing firm that they
should not launch a competing product.35 For example, Sony widely publicized its
investment in the development of the PlayStation video game product to convince other
companies not to launch competing products.36
• Second,theyleadcustomerstobelievethattheannouncingcompany’sproduct will be better than
its competitors’, which causes them to delay their purchase of competing products and wait
for the announcing company’s product to be released.37
• Third,theysignalthattheannouncer’sproductwillbeonthemarketbefore competitors’ products,
and so will become the industry standard because of its greater installed base.38 For example,
the preannouncement of the DIVX standard slowed the rate of adoption of DVD technology,
enhancing the prob- ability that DIVX would become the industry standard in digital video
recorders.39
• Fourth,theysignaltheannouncer’sintentionstosuppliersordistributorswith whom it would like
to form agreements40 and encourages other companies to produce complementary
products.41 For example, Microsoft used product pre- announcements to signal that it would
successfully enter the Web browser and video game businesses as a way to encourage
suppliers and distributors to work with it.42
However, preannouncements are not without costs. They provide information to competitors,
who might respond strategically by accelerating their development of competing products.
Moreover, they motivate customers to delay purchases of your company’s product until the
newer, and presumably better, versions have been released.43 Furthermore,
preannouncements are anticompetitive and can provoke antitrust action if your firm is large
and has a dominant market posi- tion.44 Finally, preannouncing, which can involve making
statements that do not come true, undermines the trust that your customers have in the
statements that you make.45
Despite these costs, preannouncements are a very common part of technology strategy in
industries in which customers are biased toward the adoption of products with the largest
installed base. For instance, one research study showed that software firms engage in
preannouncements almost half the time that they release products.46
A final way that companies manage customer expectations is through criticism of their
competitors’ technology.47 By criticizing your competitors’ products, you can convince
customers not to adopt their products and to adopt yours instead. Perhaps the most famous
example of an effort to criticize competitors’ products was Thomas Edison’s electrocution of
a dog, using his rival, George Westinghouse’s, electrical standard. Edison’s goal was to
persuade customers that his electricity standard was superior to Westinghouse’s, and his
gruesome act did just that.
Technical Standards
While all of the tactics described previously will help you to win a standards bat- tle,
companies cannot always predict or control the emergence of a standard, as the earlier part of
the chapter explained. Therefore, your strategy should hedge against the loss of a standards
battle. For example, you will be better off if you can make your technology work equally well
with multiple standards so that your firm will not be greatly disadvantaged if one standard
emerges rather than another.
What If You Lose?
Suppose you fight and lose a standards battle. What options are open to you?48 If the
industry only has room for one standard, then you might have to exit the market. Quitting will
be the best choice if your company would be at too much of a competi- tive disadvantage to
serve that market effectively.49 This is what Circuit City was forced to do when it lost the
digital video recorder standards battle.
Another option is to give up the fight, conform to the standard, and try to com- pete on some
other dimension, like cost, service, or features. This is what Amdahl and Hitachi did when
they lost the mainframe computer standards battle to IBM. The advantage of this strategy is
that it gives you the chance to come up with a new technology in the future that leapfrogs the
standard holder’s technology. For exam- ple, Apple first conformed to the MP3 player
standard and then, having come up with a better design, introduced a new standard with the
iPod.
However, pulling off this strategy isn’t easy. You will need to change your tech- nology to
conform to the industry standard and will have to abandon all of the capi- tal, reputation, and
learning that you have invested in it.50 As a result, your company may suffer significant
losses. For example, Rockwell and Lucent were badly dam- aged in their loss to 3Com in the
battle over the 56K modem standard.
If your industry doesn’t have an all-or-nothing standard, then you face a dif- ferent strategic
choice. Do you conform to the technical standards that have emerged, or do you try to sell
products that don’t conform to industry standards (see Figure 4)?
You might not conform to the standard and focus on a niche where you can use your
technology to meet the needs of a market segment better than the alternatives that conform to
the technical standard.51 For example, Apple Computer was able to survive for many years
without conforming to the PC standard by providing com- puters tailored to the needs of the
desktop publishing segment of the personal computer market (graphics-oriented
applications). Ultimately, however, it had to conform to the Intel standard.
Moreover, adhering to the technical standard will hinder your ability to differen- tiate your
products from those of your competitors. The aspects of your technology that conform to the
industry standard cannot be a source of competitive advantage because they must be the same
as those offered by your competitors. If you can’t be the low-cost producer, then customers
will have no reason to select your product. For example, many personal computer
manufacturers who adopted the Wintel standard lost out to Dell and Compaq because all of
the companies that adhered to the PC standard offered virtually identical products, and Dell
and Compaq were the low- cost producers.52
On the other hand, by conforming to industry standards, you will have many more customers
to target. And you will find selling your products to be easier because customers prefer
products that conform to the standard.53
Moreover, it is often difficult to focus on a niche over a long period of time because your
competitors will have the advantage of scale economies. This is why Apple finally gave in
and adopted the industry standard, letting its machines run Windows software. Over time it
became difficult for Apple to support a different standard than Microsoft because the latter’s
much larger installed base (1 billion versus 30 million) meant that it took Microsoft only
eight weeks to break even on the $1 billion cost of developing a new operating system, as
opposed to four years for Apple. Apple also could not benefit from the creation of
complementary software for its operating system because software developers needed to
write separate software for the Macintosh, and had less incentive to write for the small
installed base. Therefore, Apple earned lower profits than Microsoft on its operating system,
and had a less desirable product in terms of software availability.
Furthermore, customers put pressure on companies to adopt the dominant industry standard if
they cannot continue to offer the advantages that make differen- tiation valuable. For
instance, Sun was pushed to abandon its more powerful and more expensive microchips, and
adopt the Intel standard, when the company could not provide its network server customers
enough benefits to offset the lack of com- patibility and higher cost of its chips.55
Given the pros and cons of conforming to the industry standard, should you do it, or should
you focus on a niche? The answer to this question depends on the stage of the product life
cycle. If your market is young, and most of the customers are inno- vators or early adopters,
then you should differentiate your product from existing technical standards. At this point in
the life cycle, so little of the market has adopted the technology that convergence on a single
standard is unlikely, especially if you can offer a viable alternative. Given the advantages of
not adhering to the standard described previously, the balance falls in favor of differentiating
your product.
However, if the market is already mature, and most of the users are from the early or late
majority, then you should make your product compatible with existing technical standards. At
this point in the life cycle, so much of the market has adopted the technology that
convergence on a single standard is quite likely. Given the advantages of adhering to the
standard described previously, the balance falls in favor of conforming Defending a
Technology Standard
If your proprietary technology becomes an industry standard, then you’ll want to defend this
privileged position against the efforts of other firms to dislodge you. So how should you do
that? The answer lies in making it difficult for customers to switch to the products and
services offered by your competitors. For example, Microsoft has made it difficult for
customers to switch to competitive products by maintaining a very wide range of products
that work with the Windows operating system, even though some of those products are not
very profitable for the company. Until recently, the range of software that was compatible
with Windows locked many users into this system because there were one or two programs
that they used—niche software for games or hobbies or custom software for their industry—
that did not work with the Apple OS X operating system. Consequently, they could not switch
over to Apple computers despite the latter’s better design, superior operating sys- tem, and
lower susceptibility to viruses.
To increase your customers’ switching costs and reduce their likelihood of changing
suppliers, you can do the following:
• Makeyourproductsmoreattractivetocustomersthancompetitors’products by making the
products more functional, by adding features, or by making peripheral components available.
• Signlong-termcontractswiththeproducersofcomplementaryproductsorser- vices to ensure the
availability of complements, which enhances the value to customers of the products that you
provide.
• Makefuturegenerationsofyourproductbackwardcompatiblewithprevious generations so that
customers can easily upgrade their products (as Microsoft has done with multiple generations
of Windows software).
• Makeyourproductsorservicesincompatiblewiththealternativesofferedby your competitors.58
For example, AOL refused to allow its instant messaging service to connect to those provided
by other companies, which gave customers an incentive to remain in the AOL network.59
Technical Standards and Competition Between Systems
Technical standards often change the nature of competition from that between firms to that
between systems. When more than one technical standard exists in an industry, some products
are designed to be compatible with other products, and together they make up a technical
system. Other products, designed not to be compatible with those products, but designed to
be compatible with each other, make up a different techni- cal system. The groups of
companies that work together on the first system compete with the groups of companies that
work together on the second system. For instance, not all MP3 players are compatible with all
compression formats, creating several different MP3 systems. Thus, competition in this
business occurs at the level of the system, with Apple’s iPod/iTune system competing against
other systems that provide music players and Web sites for downloading music.
When multiple different technical systems compete in an industry, you need to decide
whether to make your products conform to all, or only some, of them. For example, until very
recently, the Apple and Microsoft computer operating systems were not compatible, so the
providers of applications software had to decide whether to offer two versions of their
products or just align with one of the systems.
If you chose to conform to only one technical standard, then you need to decide which system
is the best for your company to join. Moreover, you will have to design your products to be
compatible with the other products in that system, while making them incompatible with
products outside of the system.
Key Points
• Companiesoftenbattletocontroltechnicalstandardsbygainingthesupportof complementary
products, having a killer application, making their products backward compatible, and
managing customer and competitor expectations.
• Ifyouloseastandardsbattle,youcanexitthemarket,conformtothestandard and compete on
another dimension, or focus on a niche and meet its needs without conforming to the
standard.
• Ifyourtechnologybecomestheindustrystandard,thenyouneedtodefendit against the efforts of
other firms to dislodge it by keeping customer switching costs high.
• Technicalstandardsoftenleadtocompetitionbetweensystemsofcompanies, rather than between
individual organizations.
Open Versus Closed Standards
Companies need to decide whether to create an open standard—a standard for which
specifications are known by other companies—or a closed standard—a sys- tem for which
those specifications are not known.
There are many advantages to having an open standard. First, an open standard will make it
easier for other companies to understand how your products work and, therefore, how to
build complementary products.60 For example, JVC’s decision to establish an open standard
encouraged movie studios to provide more video content on VHS than on Betamax, and led
the video recorder market to tip to the VHS standard.61
In fact, by attracting the providers of complementary products, an open standard can create a
positive feedback loop that benefits a company. The more complemen- tary products that are
available for a product, the more customers are interested in buying it; and the more
customers that are interested in buying a product, the more companies are interested in
providing complementary products for it.
Take, for example, the case of the open-source software provider Linux, which provides
software that any user can license for free in return for licensing any addi- tions that they
make to the software at no charge. As Figure 5 shows, the more people that used Linux
software, the more software applications were created for it; and the more software
applications that were created for Linux, the more people used it.62
Second, open standards encourage other companies, which might develop supe- rior
alternatives, to adopt your technology, mitigating the threat of competition.63 For example,
Sun Microsystems brought out minicomputers that used the UNIX operating system and
adopted an open approach to its software, publishing its spec- ifications and interface
protocols.64 This open system made it possible for other com- panies to write software for
Sun’s platform, which reduced their incentive to develop their own alternatives.65
Third, open standards allow you to generate a large installed base very quickly by attracting
more users than a single company can support.66 For example, Microsoft generated a much
larger installed base for its DOS operating system than Apple did for
While an open standard benefits companies, it also has risks. By opening up your technology
to other companies, you run the risk of losing control over your technology and,
consequently, sales.68 For example, Palm used open-source coding for its PDAs to increase
adoption and to encourage the development of a technical standard. However, this approach
made Palm vulnerable to competitors who could produce the PDA hardware at a lower cost
than Palm.
By using an open standard, you also incur the risk that licensees might change your
technology in a way that makes it unnecessary for them to pay you royalties. Thus, you might
make less money off of your technology than if you had created a closed standard and never
licensed it to others. For example, AMD was able to get out of paying royalties on Intel’s K5
microprocessors after having made modifica- tions to Intel’s initial technology, undermining
Intel’s revenue stream from that technology.69
Furthermore, an open standard demonstrates to your competitors how your technology works,
making it easier for them to imitate it. Because your competitors will be more likely to
leapfrog your technology if they can imitate it, having an open standard could undermine
your competitive advantage.
Two different types of open standards exist, each of which creates different opportunities and
problems for managers and entrepreneurs. Some open standards are proprietary, like
Microsoft Windows. The standard is open because Microsoft shares information about the
operating system so that other companies can provide complementary products. However, the
Windows standard is owned and controlled by Microsoft. Other open standards are
nonproprietary, like the Linux operating sys- tem, which is not owned or controlled by a
single company.
Proprietary and nonproprietary open standards both have their advantages and disadvantages.
Nonproprietary open standards benefit companies by making their products better for
customers. First, they are neutral, which means that customers
More Users
More More Contributors Applications
More Developers
don’t have to accept the strategic direction of the owner of the standard, or its power over the
development of their products. Second, they do not require customers to pay royalties, thus
lowering costs. Third, they are easier to use and customize because more information about
them is provided to users.
However, nonproprietary open standards create several strategic problems for providers.
First, they do not allow companies to control quality or the development of the standard in a
way that benefits their products, as Microsoft has done with the Windows operating
system.71 Second, they do not provide strong incentives for com- panies to support their
customers.72 Third, they open up markets to competition, which can undermine a provider’s
competitive position, as occurred when computer operating systems switched from IBM to
Unix.
Opensystemsarevaluablebecausetheyfacilitatethecreationofcomplemen- tary products, create
a positive feedback effect, permit the rapid creation of a large installed base, and discourage
other companies from competing against your technology.
• Opensystemsriskthelossofcontrolovertechnology,whichcouldleadtoa decline in sales.
• Twotypesofopensystemsexist;some,liketheMicrosoftoperatingsystem,are proprietary, while
others, like the Linux operating system, are nonproprietary.
• Nonproprietaryopenstandardshavetheadvantageofbeingmoreattractiveto customers; they are
neutral, don’t require royalty payments, and are easier for customers to use.
• Proprietaryopenstandardshelpcompaniesbyreducingcompetition,bygiving them control over
the development of technology, and by providing a strong incentive to support the system
KEY TERMS
Backward Compatibility: Making a product or service work with previous generations of
products or services.
Installed Base: The number of users of a product at a
Open Standard: standard whose specifications are known by other companies.
Preannouncements: The announcements of product release dates before the actual release
occurs.
Technical Standards: The specifications that are necessary to make sure that the components
of a technical system are compatible with each other.
PUTTING IDEAS INTO PRACTICE
1. Identifying Technical Standards The purpose of this exercise is to identify all of the
technical stan- dards that affect a laptop computer. Begin by mak- ing a list of all of the
components of a laptop computer with wireless capability. Then, identify if there is a
technical standard that governs each of these components. (If you know the name of the
specific technical standard, that’s great. Write it.
2. How Standards Emerge Identify three technical standards. Investigate how those standards
came into existence. (They don’t all have to have come into existence the same way.) Explain
why the mechanisms that you identified accounted for the emergence of the standards
Disclosure Paradox: The inability to get others to contract for knowledge unless the
knowledge is dis-closed, combined with the unwillingness for others to pay for knowledge
once it has been disclosed.
Exclusive License: license that gives only one party the right to use a technology.
Free Ride: The tendency of one party to let others do the work necessary to receive a benefit.
Hold-up: The tendency of one party to a contractual agreement to take advantage of the
other's vulnerabilities to renegotiate the terms of the agreement.
Horizontal Alliance: partnership between firms at the same stage of the value chain to work
together to achieve a common goal.
Joint Venture: A legal partnership between two firms to own equity in a third firm formed by
the two
Paruicts
Licensing: form of business, under which one firm permits another to use its technology in
return for the payment of a fee.
Nonexclusive License: license that grants many parties the right to use a technology.
Outsourcing: A mode of business in which a company assigns some aspect of its operations
to another company under contract.
Strategic Alliance: partnership between two firms to work together to achieve a common
goal.
Vertically Integrated: mode of doing business in which the company owns more than one part
of the value chain.